Campaign for Cambridge Freedoms
31st March
2004 - today sees the publication of a draconian
intellectual property policy, which will significantly curtail
academic freedom at Cambridge. It is scheduled for a Discussion in the
Regent House on the 11th
May, followed by a vote. Diarise this; we have to defeat it.
Background - the IP Dispute at Cambridge
Until 2001, the copyrights and other intellectual property rights in
academic work at the University belonged (with a few narrow
exceptions) to the people who did the work. In 2001, a policy
change was made for staff funded by research contracts: all their
intellectual property rights (with a few narrow exceptions) now belong
to the University. This passed unremarked and, initially, unenforced.
In 2002, the Vice-Chancellor proposed
to extend this expropriation to tenured academic staff as well.
This time, people took note. We set up the Campaign for Cambridge
Freedoms and produced an analysis
of the likely effects. At a Discussion in the Regent House in October
2002, the great majority of speakers expressed outrage. A speech by Tom Körner became a
classic. We got wide press coverage including the Observer,
the Telegraph,
the Wall
Street Journal and the BBC, to whom
our Vice Chancellor said "The university has a right to a share
because I think there are very few true individuals. Most people have
to rely on others". This collectivist view did not go down very well!
The University's governing body, the Council, reacted to this outrage
in the usual way - by setting up a committee to report back once the
fuss had died down. This committee, chaired by IP lawyer Bill Cornish,
published its report
almost a year later, in August 2003. It suggested that the University
should take only patent rights, as it wouldn't be politically possible
to do any more for the time being. There was a Discussion
of the Report on the 21st October. The mood of the Regent House
was against even Cornish's compromise, and in favour of restoring our
rights as they were before 2001. Yet the detailed regulations now
published by Cornish in 2004 are closer to the 2002 policy than to his
2003 compromise. They will give University bureaucrats a veto over
many aspects of academic life that were previously under the sole
control of academics.
The Proposed Regulations
We could summarise the 2002 proposals as `the University takes
everything', the 2003 proposals as `the University takes only patents'
and the 2004 proposals as `the University takes everything except
copyright, narrowly defined'.
Although the proposals leave us with default ownership of
copyright, they make a large number of other claims which undermine
this apparent liberty:
- First, they will assert central ownership of all intellectual
property rights that are acquired by registration, such as patents,
plant-breeders' rights, registered designs and trademarks.
-
Second, the University will take a range of rights related to
copyright, such as database rights in compilations. They will also
take a number of ancilliary copyrights where University equipment is
involved, such as in typographical designs and sound recordings.
-
Third, the University will take many further rights by contractual
agreement. Any external funding of research will cause resulting
copyrights or confidential information to belong to either the
sponsor or the University, but not to the creator. This will be the
case not just for the contract research staff but also for tenured
academics involved in the project.
These will have a number of effects, both on academics' freedom of
enquiry and on our employment rights.
Effects on Academic Freedom of Enquiry
Quite apart from the policy's effects on academics involved in
business - which I'll discuss below - many academics with no interest
in business will find their work encumbered by IP claims which will
involve them in extra bureaucracy, or make it harder for them to move
elsewhere. Many students will be asked to sign away their IP in
project and thesis work. There will be both direct and indirect
effects.
-
Perhaps the most direct effect will be on biological scientists who
sequence DNA and put the results in the public domain. The University
claim on the database rights in their work will mean that they will
need permission to do this. In fact, people who have contributed to
public-domain databases since 2001 - and who have been funded with
research contracts - have already polluted those databases with
potential claims of University ownership. Even if they sincerely
believed that they could place this material in the public domain, the
database rights actually belonged to the University. So someone could
buy these rights from a future University administration and use them
to sue the public-domain databases and their users - just as SCO is
suing Linux and its users. The reputational damage to the University,
and the harm to the public good, would be colossal. In fact, a Royal
Society inquiry chaired by a former pro-vice-chancellor of the
university recommended
the abolition of database rights altogether. (After I raised the DNA
issue in Council, the last sentence of clause 7 was inserted, which
says that the University won't sell these rights on without consulting
their creators. That's nowhere near good enough - these rights must be
relinquished for good.)
-
Another example is clause 7's claim of rights in typographic
arrangements of published works, where these are made with University
equipment. This appears to presume that published works, such as this
web page, are published by the University rather than by the
individual responsible for them (the typographical arrangement
copyright goes by default to the publisher - see the Copyright,
Designs and Patents Act section 9). This would give the University
the right to demand that I take down the page, even if it were hosted
on a non-University server. Even if such censorship were not practised
on a daily basis, its mere possibility should be opposed. In fact, a
University
report earlier described academic ownership of copyright as ``an
important guarantee of academic freedom' and strongly recommended that
``No change should be made to this basic rule.''
- Another likely direct effect is on academic visitors. Clause 10
of the policy provides for all visitors to be bound by the
regulations. When once in the past a US university asked me to sign an
NDA and IP transfer agreement on visiting, I simply refused. So would
most smart people. If this obnoxious practice becomes the norm in
Cambridge, visitors just won't come here. We will be isolated.
There are more global reasons why individual academic ownership of
intellectual property is important. See Larry Lessig's latest book, or my detailed analysis of the 2002 IP
proposal. Over the last twenty years, a coalition of drug companies,
the music industry and software publishers have pushed for ever more
extensive copyright laws, which are being used to control culture and
enclose the digital commons. Academics have been prominent in the
fightback, through such diverse initiatives as the Public Library of
Science, other open publishing
initiatives, the Free Software
movement and the Creative
Commons. MIT, our US partner in CMI, has MIT Open Courseware.
The strategic effects will be even worse. The policy is the latest in
a sequence of reforms started by the last Vice-Chancellor to turn
Cambridge from a decentralised organisation controlled by the academic
staff, much like the partners in a law firm, into a corporate entity
in which power is wielded centrally by the Vice-Chancellor acting
through the Unified Administrative Service. This reform has fostered
bureaucratic empire-building and pushed the University from profit
into loss. It has undermined our autonomy and our working conditions.
If we cannot use our democratic mechanisms to draw a line in the sand
on even this issue, then the depredations will continue. We've had an
email
policy that threatened academic staff with the sack if we ever
sent an email that might offend anybody; we've had departmental
administrators blocking the use
of departmental email to people wishing to discuss IP issues with
colleagues. Most shocking of all was the case of
Mike Clark: our Research Services Division agreed, without his
knowledge or consent, that he would submit all his relevant
publications for vetting by a drug company that had licensed one of
the University's patents. That's our future once RSD controls all our
IP. And consultancy's next. Now that the demons of envy have been
unleashed, Council members are starting to talk about requiring people
who earn money from consulting to contribute a percentage to the
Chest.
Oh, and by the way, Regulation 27 in the new proposal will prevent
campaigns such as this one from using the University's crest in
future. We use it in order to emphasise that we the academics, not the
Unified Administrative Service, are the University. Sir Humphrey
doesn't seem to appreciate that.
Effects on Academic Earnings and Employment Rights
In this sad world of ours, doctors and lawyers earn more than poets or
philosophers. At some universities this is reflected in salary
differentials; at a good US university, a medical professor might get
$400,000, a computer scientist $200,000 and a poet $100,000. Cambridge
has historically been different. All professors earn the same basic
pay (less than $100,000), and only a few get small bonuses. But we are
free to earn money on the side. Poets write books; computer scientists
write software; lawyers plead cases in court; and medics see private
patients.
If the new policy gets through, many academics wishing to earn side
income involving creative intellectual activity will be beholden to
the University for permissions, licenses or letters of comfort. Some
of the richest academics - the medics, the lawyers and the writers of
popular books - will probably escape, but people like scientists,
technologists and language-teaching entrepreneurs will be caught. Just
as in a typical national taxation system, the rich will get off
scot-free, the poor will pay a bit, and the middle class will bear the
brunt.
Consider the following cases.
- Cambridge academics will no longer be permitted to register domain
names, as these are registrable intellectual property rights. This
will affect not just our ability to engage in business, but also our
ability to brand our research projects (as with G3card, with which I raised a lot of
money for the University), and even our charitable activities. For
example, when I set up the Foundation for Information Policy Research,
one of the first things I did - before even registering the company -
was to register fipr.org.
-
Suppose you teach a lecture course at Cambridge, and give it elsewhere
during the vacation for extra money. At present, you own all the
intellectual property in the course, so that's OK. You can even turn
your course into a book and sell it. Under the new regulations, the
University will claim the typographic-design copyright in your
Powerpoint slides, if they were made with University equipment. So you
must either buy your own computer, or accept the risk that the
University can at some future time demand a share of your lecturing
fees. Also, if you prepared illustrations for your book using a
University computer, you might be obliged to hand over some of your
royalties. Also, the University claims a free perpetual license to all
your teaching materials, so it can set up in competition with you.
-
A lecturer in Korean writes a language teaching book, based on
Cambridge teaching, to compete with the expensive Linguaphone course.
Although she owns the copyright in the course material, the University
owns the database rights in the vocabulary. If she used a
University-owned computer to set the text, the University owns the
typographical-design copyright, and if the microphone used to record
the spoken lessons were University-owned, the University would also
own the sound recordings. Similar problems will face academics
interested in music, drama and other subjects that involve recording
equipment.
-
Two computer science lecturers wrote and maintain a compiler whose
unregistered trademark is made up of their names. The new regulations
empower the University to register that trademark and control its use
in the future.
-
Suppose you are a professor of archaeology who has a collection of
Roman artefacts, built up over twenty years and bought with your own
money. You create a database of your collection and its context. This
database will in future belong to the University, limiting your
freedom to move elsewhere on retirement.
-
When I was a research student, I financed my study by setting up the
abstracts journal in my field, as a joint business venture with my
thesis adviser. This would require University permission under the new
regime; the University's ownership of database rights in the
compilation, and of typographical rights in the publication, would
give RSD a veto on such projects.
-
The biological and clinical sciences may be worst affected, as RSD
control of the database rights in all sequence data they produce will
potentially poison all public-domain databases to which this data is
contributed (such as the Human Genome project) and is also likely to
entangle research collaborations with other organisations. In the
Council debate on this, I pointed out that the University could sell
its residual rights in such data to an entrepreneur such as Craig
Venter who might then use it to mount a legal challenge to the
database's public-domain status. As a result, the policy has been
modified so that the University must consult with the creators of a
database right before selling it to a third party - but the creators
do not get a veto.
Some high-profile University academics will escape the effects of the
new policy. For example, the next popular science book from Stephen
Hawking will probably be unaffected - so long as the author is careful
not to compile the index, but have it compiled by the publishers (so
that only copyright, rather than database rights, are involved).
But these will be in the minority. Most academics either produce
creative output spanning more than one kind of intellectual property
right, or collaborate with externally-funded research students. In the
case of academics whose work produces database material (such as DNA
sequences) the new regulations could extinguish any entrepreneurial
freedom, as well as the freedom to move to a better job elsewhere. In
the case of academics whose work produces material such as designs or
recordings that are claimed only when University equipment is used, a
choice has to be made of whether to risk these rights or to buy all
the necessary computers and other equipment out of one's own pocket.
Given that the University has traditionally given academics free PCs
and network access, this will be equivalent to a salary cut of several
hundred pounds a year.
Economic Effects
The IP reforms were initially justified on economic grounds - that
they would help the UK economy by promoting technology transfer, and
that they would make money for the University. Yet there is a very
substantial body of economic research which shows that university
tech transfer operations mostly lose money. Occasionally, a University
makes a windfall; but on balance it would have been better to put the
money on the roulette wheel at a casino.
So will the expropriation of Cambridge patents and other IP make money
for the economy? Here too the evidence is strongly negative. The definitive study of the
Cambridge Phenomenon argued that the large number of high-tech
businesses spun off from the University owed a lot to the fact that
academics own our patents and copyrights, so those who were inclined
to doing business start-ups could do so without having to appease
University bureaucrats at every step and hand over most of the
resulting profits. The second edition remarked that it was probably
already harder, from an IP perspective, for academics to drive
spin-out creation. The Cambridge technology transfer scene is also
very diverse at present; creating a University monopoly on academic IP
is the worst thing that could happen for entrepreneurship. Most local
`business angels' believe that drastically tightening Cambridge's IP
regime will kill the goose that lays the golden eggs.
For more, including links to relevant academic research, see our detailed
analysis of the 2002 policy.
Other Issues
There are elaborate provisions for the University to set up an
internal arbitration system, and even an appeal process. This raises
an issue of natural justice, namely whether the University ought to be
a judge in cases between it and its employees. Recent history also
casts some doubt on the ability of our administration to adjudicate
fairly between junior and senior staff.
There are many details in the policy that appear designed to supply
the arbitrators and lawyers with work. For example, Regulation 20 says
that if staff members cannot agree who made what share of an
invention, any royalties will be split equally between them. In those
fields where it's common for a senior researcher to provide 60% of the
ideas and four junior staff 10% each, there will be a temptation for
junior staff to dispute; once this is realised, the temptation will be
for senior staff to involve as few juniors as they can. This will
surely undermine trust, and the University's broader educational
mission.
As our most recent Nobel Laureate Sir John
Sulston argues, the freedom to share information quickly, without
hindrance from patent lawyers or bureaucrats, is critical to effective
research. We must defend this freedom.
Ross Anderson
31st March 2004
The committee members of the Campaign for Cambridge Freedoms are:
There has been significant press coverage of the first round of
Cambridge's IP war, including articles in the Observer,
the Telegraph,
the Cambridge
Evening News, ZDNET,
THES, the Wall Street
Journal, the BBC and Varsity.
There is a mailing list
you can join, and there is also some discussion of the issue on the
ucam.change.governance newsgroup. (We also have our own Dilbert :-)